

A debate has erupted, particularly on the right, in response to a recent Tucker Carlson monologue on how āWashington eliteā policy choices, in particular international trade liberalization, have systematically (and perhaps nefariously) harmed members of Americaās working class, dooming them to lives of drugs, isolation and despair. If this view were assigned to Carlson and his supporters alone, a few tweets in response would suffice. It has not, however, remained on Fox News, instead being promulgated and praised, though refined, by more thoughtful commentators and analysts. Among those is the University of Virginiaās Brad Wilcox and the Niskanen Centerās Sam Hammond in a new essay in The Atlantic called āWhat Tucker Carlson Gets Right.ā
I tend to agree with this essayās larger points, having myself written about the serious, and relatively new, problems that Americans face when forced to adjust to severe disruptions, whether they come from trade, technology, culture or anything elseāproblems caused or exacerbated by bad government policies in desperate need of reform. On the specific issue of trade policy, however, I fear Wilcox and Hammond go far off course when they target the āelite policy choiceā of liberalized U.S. trade with China for particular scorn. While Chinese import competition worked out great for Americaās wealthy, they argue, it was a disaster for the working class:
The work of the MIT economist David Autor and his colleagues, in particular, indicates that dramatic and sudden increases in global trade with China starting around 2000 affected both menās earnings and their marriageability. In their words, āTrade shocks to manufacturing industries have particularly negative impacts on the labor market prospects of men and degrade their marriage-market value along multiple dimensions: diminishing their relative earningsāparticularly at the lower segment of the distributionāreducing their physical availability in trade-impacted labor markets, and increasing their participation in risky and damaging behaviors.ā They add that āadverse shocks to the supply of āmarriageableā men reduce the prevalence of marriage ⦠but raise the fraction of children born to young and unwed mothers and living in poor single-parent households.ā
These intertwined problems, then, were not the fault of a spontaneous decline in personal virtue. They were the fault of Washington elites who pursued a naive path of normalized trade with China that, in a matter of years, gutted millions of moderately educated workers of their decent-paying jobs, and without support in the way of adjustment assistance or wage insurance. Our elites had too much faith in a laissez-faire ideology that sees labor markets as automatically self-correcting but, in fact, exacted a terrible toll on scores of working-class families across the United States. (emphasis mine) The āpolicy choiceā here, which I subsequently confirmed with Hammond to be sure, relates to the 2000 U.S. law to grant China āpermanent normal trade relationsā (PNTR) upon its subsequent entry into the World Trade Organization in 2001āthe starting point for the now-famed Autor (and colleagues Dorn and Hanson, widely known collectively by the rockstar acronym ADH) āChina Shock.ā With this view, Wilcox and Hammond today find ample company on the right, including in the Trump administration, as it has become increasingly fashionable to cast PNTR as a āmistakeā responsible for the China Shock and the WTO as responsible for (and not equipped to handle) Chinaās rise.
However, this argument (i.e., that PNTR was an erroneous āelite policy choiceā that disproportionately benefited the elites, directly drove the China Shock, and, combined with elitesā other ālaissez-faireā policies, permanently scarred Americaās working class) suffers from several flawsāflaws that, when combined, prove fatal for the āPNTR thesis.ā
First and most obviously, the thesis ignores the documented benefits of increased U.S. trade with China over the last two decadesābenefits that often accrue to the U.S. working class and manufacturing sector.
For example, even if one were to treat the China Shock literature as gospel, various studies have found that trade with China in the 2000s still provided ample benefits for American consumersāa group that of course includes those directly harmed by the China Shock. A 2018 paper, for example, found that Chinese import competition between 2000-07 had substantial āpro-competitive effectsā on U.S. firms and generated over $202 billion in consumer benefits via lower pricesāequal to $101,250 per manufacturing job lost, as calculated by the China Shock papers. A 2017 study found similarly impressive consumer gains. Another paper found that the consumer benefits of trade, which are already heavily tilted toward Americaās poor and middle class, were even more so for Chinese imports, because these U.S. consumers are more likely than their richer counterparts to shop at places like Target and Walmart. One can argue that these consumer benefits are cold comfort to someone who lost a job to Chinese import competition, but they are nevertheless real, widespread and important.
Chinese imports have also been found to generate substantial benefits for American companies, including manufacturers (and their workers). One series of papers found that Chinese import competition encouraged, quite logically, many American manufacturing firms to invest and innovate moreāanother āpro-competitiveā effect. Another paper found net welfare benefits (i.e., an economy's overall prosperity and living standards) from the China Shock for U.S. manufacturing (and non-manufacturing) across regions. Just last week, the San Francisco Fed found that, about 56 cents of every dollar that Americans spent on āMade in Chinaā imports last year actually went to American firms and workersāthe highest share of any country. That same study also found that one-third of all Chinese imports were intermediate goods (e.g., manufacturing inputs like auto parts) used by American companies to produce globally competitive goods and services. With respect to these types of global value chains, the WTO estimates that China is the top user/exporter of Made-In-America manufacturing inputs and the second largest source of inputs for American manufacturers, behind only Canada. Then, of course, there are the benefits that American farmers and workers derive from exporting to China, the United Statesā third largest export destination.
There is also evidence that many U.S. manufacturers adapted in the face of trade competition (and automation) and ended up hiring more Americans, just in different areas. As the FTās Gillian Tett just recapped, ābetween 1977 and 2012ā¦employees in ānon-manufacturing plantsā that were owned by āmanufacturing firmsā rose from 13m to 23m, primarily due to an explosion in service sector jobs such as design and IT. As a result, by 2012 the USās āmanufacturingā companies employed slightly more workers than in 1977. Moreover, that was not because of business churn: 75 per cent of the āmanufacturingā job losses in this period occurred at companies which remained in business, and it was the incumbents which opened most of the non-manufacturing plants. In plain English, this means that as Chinese competition hit, Americaās āmanufacturingā groups quietly re-engineered themselvesā¦. [T]hey increasingly hire service-sector workers, as their output soars.ā She then cites other research showing that in many parts of America (though not all) āvanishing manufacturing jobs have been replaced by new service work.ā
Finally, other economists have raised questions, directly or indirectly, about whether the China Shock literature is telling a complete story when it comes to Chinese imports, U.S. manufacturing jobs and related issues. A 2018 paper, for example, found that, after accounting for manufacturing supply chains and those aforementioned intermediate inputs, the overall effect of the China Shock on American jobs and wages was quite positive. Another paper from last year used a dynamic āgeneral equilibriumā model to find far fewer manufacturing job losses caused by the trade shock (only 15 percent of the observed decline between 2000 and 2007), and net welfare gains across regions (even in manufacturing). Another found that, while the China Shock produced losses for certain groups, it generated overall gains in social welfare. Another found offsetting job gains in U.S. manufacturing exports and services, while yet another found one-third fewer manufacturing job losses and much different regional effects when using value-added, instead of gross, trade flows (and that job losses basically ended in 2008). Other experts have raised methodological questions about the China Shock findings (including on marriage). And finally others demand broader perspective about the China Shock claims: For example, DeLong notes the concurrent and offsetting growth of other āworking classā jobs (Krugman too), while Irwin (citing a 2014 Robert Lawrence paper) adds that āimports from China may have resulted in involuntary displacement of 97,000 manufacturing workers per year (on average, adjusted to account for voluntary separations), but that is less than one-fifth of total involuntary job loss in manufacturing and less than 5 percent of all involuntary job losses over the same period.ā (Autor himself calls the 2 million figure an āupper boundā that includes around 1 million non-manufacturing jobs, while his new marriage paper acknowledges that the āanalysis does not imply that surging import competition from China over the last two decades has been the sole or primary driver of these [marriage and childbirth] trendsā but only a āplausible contributor.ā)
Indeed, a look at the relatively steady decline in manufacturing jobs as a share of the U.S. workforce shows only a modest change before and after PNTR passed and China entered the WTO:

The moral of this literature review is not that Chinese import competition produces only rainbows and butterflies in the United States or that there are no problems in the U.S. labor market or certain communities, but simply that thereās another, rather large side to the China Shock coin. That side shows the substantial net benefits from trade (certainly not only or āoverwhelminglyā for āelitesā) and reveals the China Shock issue to be more uncertain and complex than the one-sided, myopic caricature painted by many PNTR/China trade critics and more similar to the standard trade story: discrete, but more concentrated, pains versus larger, but more diffuse (and harder to see), benefits. Thatās a story worth telling, as are the significant issues arising from American workersā failure to adjust to trade and other disruptions, but itās not nearly the widespread āAmerican carnageā you hear so often from those pushing the PNTR thesis.
Second, the PNTR thesis ignores the reality of Chinaās entry into the WTO and its export competitiveness. For starters, PNTR did not actually open the United States to Chinese imports: since 1980 the United States government had granted China ānormal trade relationsā (NTR) status on an annual basis, with Congress routinely defeating legislation to deny China this treatmentāeven right after the Tiananmen Square protests and the election of a president (Clinton) who ran against NTR. As a result, Chinese imports to the United States increased more than six-fold in the decade preceding PNTR, and the rational expectation of most U.S. importers was more of the same. Chinese imports increased even more after PNTR, likely assisted by the certainty of āpermanentā trade relations, but itās a myth to say that some isolated, āeliteā policy choice in the late 1990s first exposed the U.S. market (and U.S. workers) to Chinese import competition.
More importantly, however, is the ample evidence showing that the PNTR āelite policy choiceā was not the only, or even main, driver of the China Shock that occurred in United States in the late 1990s and 2000s. A 2017 paper, for example, found that approximately two-thirds of the impact of Chinaās WTO entry on U.S. manufactured goods prices (and thus on U.S. manufacturers and their workers) came not from PNTR but from Chinaās own tariff reductions resulting from WTO entry. (Chinese import tariffs went from 15 percent in 2000 to 9 percent in 2006.) The China Shock papers themselves emphasize that Chinaās internal reformsāon privatization, trading rights, and (again) import liberalization, often in response to new WTO commitmentsāwere major contributors to Chinaās export competitiveness in the late ā90s and 2000s. (A view subsequently confirmed elsewhere.) In other words, PNTR probably accelerated Chinese exports to the United States (though some experts question the magnitude of this driver), but Chinaās own reformsāfar beyond the control of those Washington āelitesā now said to be at āfaultā āalso fueled the āChina Shock.ā
Furthermore, itās a stretch to claim, as many do, that Chinaās WTO accession was really all that āshockingāāat least for anyone paying the least bit of attention to U.S. trade policy in the 1990s (which, youād assume, would include U.S. manufacturers and unions). China first applied to join the WTO (under its predecessor the GATT) in 1985, then reapplied in 1995 when the WTO took over, and finally acceded to the body in 2001. Chinaās accession over this time involved dozens of bilateral and multilateral (āworking partyā) meetings, negotiating texts, disclosures andāas noted aboveāinternal reforms. Chinaās final accession packageāa āWorking Party Reportā and āProtocol of Accessionā plus liberalization schedules for goods and servicesācontained hundreds of pages of commitments (by far the most of any acceding member up to that point and still today considered to be some of the deepest ever), including many āWTO-plusā commitments that the United States and other members dictated (via bilateral accession agreements) and have since used, for example, to challenge Chinese laws through dispute settlement or to restrict Chinese imports (more on these below). Notably, the United States was the final holdout among large industrialized nations to approve Chinaās WTO accession via bilateral negotiations, with U.S. negotiators demanding evermore concessions from the Chinese government over a contentious 13-year period. Meanwhile, U.S. trade representatives for multiple presidents from each major party frequently consulted with Congress and the ĀĀprivate sector, including labor unions, at every step of the process (as required by U.S. law). Thus, from a simple legal and historical perspective, there was nothing āshockingā about the China Shock.
Itās an even bigger stretch to assert that, based on the facts at the time, Washington policymakers really had much of a āchoiceā when it came to permanently normalizing trade relations with China in the late 1990s (a move that every other WTO member had done years earlier). In this regard, I recommend Phil Levyās 2018 piece in Foreign Affairs on the only actual alternatives to PNTR. Each of themāletting China in the WTO but continuing the annual NTR process or even raising tariffs on Chinese goods, or keeping China from the WTO entirelyāwas clearly inferior, in terms of economics and geopolitics, to granting PNTR. Indeed, denying more than 1 billion people (many of whom were in abject poverty) in an modernizing economy access to an open multilateral trade organizationāone that already included communist Cuba and for decades and tolerated Eastern Bloc command-and-control economies and dozens of āsocialistā countries with pervasive state-owned industriesāwas simply not realistic, especially given what policymakers knew (or possibly could have known) at the time about Chinaās economic reforms. This last point bears emphasis: As noted above, the reforms that China undertook during its WTO accession, often in direct response to WTO requirements (and member demands), were so substantial as to driveāalong with additional reforms made shortly after accessionāChinaās incredible export competitiveness. To assert that U.S. policymakers in the 1990s were somehow ānaĆÆve,ā that they should have somehow known that these reforms would cease or reverse a decade later under different leadership (twice removed), and thus deny China entry into the WTO or deny PNTR (becoming the only WTO Member to do so), is applying an impossible standard that only Miss Cleo could meet.
Third, the PNTR thesis ignores the missed opportunities since Chinaās WTO accession, especially the unused checks on Chinese trade abuses that were among Chinaās (allegedly weak) WTO commitments. As noted above, China did undertake substantial trade and economic liberalization before and shortly after entering the WTO, but problems have undoubtedly arisen since then. As my Cato colleagues James Bacchus, Simon Lester, and Huan Zhu just wrote, however, most of those problems can be addressed through WTO dispute settlement, whose rulings China tends to follow (arguably moreso, it should be noted, than the United States). If these new cases have not been pursued (which they often havenāt, especially in the Trump administration), then that is an āelite policy choiceā worth condemningānot the original decision to admit China to the WTO in the first place. Indeed, it is either mistaken or misleading to claim that Chinaās WTO accession terms were weak and that the WTO has utterly failed to discipline Chinaās unfair trade practices when the sole means of imposing such disciplineādispute settlementāand the āWTO-plusā rules China agreed to (including on intellectual property) have never been fully utilized. This is declaring defeat before ever firing a shot.
Other āelite policy choicesā since the passage of PNTR also deserve scrutiny, such as U.S. withdrawal from the Trans-Pacific Partnership, which was in large part designed to contain Chinaās geopolitical ambitions; tax and trade policies that inhibit American companiesā global competitiveness; a general failure to reform state and federal adjustment assistance and worker retraining programs in the face of immense trade/technological/cultural disruption; or the imposition of tax, occupational licensing, zoning, and other policies that actively discourage labor dynamism. These policies are indeed worthy of criticism and debate, but they have nothing to do with the original choiceāif you can even call it thatāto pass PNTR, allow China to join the WTO, or otherwise ānormalizeā trade with China.
Fourth, the PNTR thesis ignores the many non-ālaissez faireā mechanisms in place for decadesāmechanisms that simply didnāt work. A core tenet of the PNTR thesis is that American elites simply opened the floodgates to Chinese imports with only a timid threat of WTO disputes to protect American workers from āunfairā Chinese imports. This ignores, however, the mountain of government interventions that have been utilizedāat the federal level aloneāto restrict Chinese imports, otherwise protect or subsidize American manufacturers, or assist American workers.
On trade, the United States still maintains significant tariffs and tariff-rate quotas on imports of āsensitiveā products like trucks, apparel, footwear and food. According to the group Global Trade Alert, moreover, the United States has also long been one of the most frequent users of āharmfulā non-tariff government trade interventionsāones that far outnumber its āliberalizingā measures over the same period. This includes hundreds of special duties (ātrade remediesā like anti-dumping and anti-subsidy measures) on all sorts of Chinese imports, most often using a special ānon-market economyā anti-dumping methodology that practically ensures sky-high duty rates (often more than 100 percent) on those goodsācoincidentally, one of those āWTO-plusā accession commitments special to China and a few other economies. These duties are specifically intended to offset āunfairā trade and subsidies that injure US manufacturers and workers, andāas the numbers indicateāAmerican companies and labor unions have been quite successful in petitioning for them. Dozens of other Chinese imports are barred from the U.S. market as a result of āSection 337ā actions that target intellectual property rights violations. Chinese investment, meanwhile, can be (and has been) restricted by the Committee on Foreign Investment in the United States (CFIUS), and US technology exports to China are often blocked on national security grounds.
And letās not forget about the auto bailouts, the steel industry bailouts, the alternative energy subsidies, the manufacturing tax credits, the ExIm Bank loans, procurement preferences like Buy American and Davis-Bacon, the Jones Act and the PVSA, and the billions of other taxpayer dollars that the United States has doled out to āblue collarā industries and workers over the last few decades at the federal level alone.
The United States government has also repeatedly tried to subsidize and retrain workers, as I noted a few years ago in National Review:
Most notably, the Trade Adjustment Assistance (TAA) program, intended to subsidize U.S. workers affected by import competition, is a notorious failure: Not only are TAAās costs too high and its eligibility criteria too loose, but multiple studies commissioned by the Labor Department have found that TAA participants are worse off, as measured by future wages and benefits, than similarly situated jobless individuals outside the program. (TAA also breeds the misconception that trade is somehow different from, and worse than, other forms of beneficial economic disruption, such as automation.)
Other federal job-training programs are similarly inefficacious. A 2011 Government Accountability Office study, for example, found that the federal government had 47 different, often overlapping job-training programs spanning nine federal agencies at a cost of $18 billion per year. Only five had been subject to any sort of impact analysis since 2004; thus, ālittle is known about the effectiveness of [the] employment and training programsā identified. A 2014 reform of this system, the Workforce Innovation and Opportunity Act, eliminated 15 programs (while maintaining the rest, despite their long history of subpar results) but failed to impose any sort of rigorous multi-site evaluation and accountability system. Without these simple reforms, or other, more radical ones, there is no way to ensure that the āreformedā federal job programs wonāt continue their long record of failing American workers and taxpayers. (For an update on TAAās problems, see this recent Wall Street Journal piece.) As I argued in National Review at the time, these and other government programs raise serious concerns when it comes to helping American workers adjust to trade and other shocks, and they need to be reformed. But that doesnāt change the simple fact that they do exist and have for decades. And itās their (and the aforementioned othersā) existence alone, which unequivocally refutes the claim that US policymakers simply passed PNTR and walked away from the American working class due to some sort of rigid adherence to laissez faire ideology.
The real problem was that these interventions just didnāt work very well. A classic example is the US steel industry, whose companies and workers since the 1970s have arguably received more government assistance than any industry in the country. This includes hundreds of trade remedy measures and other import restrictions; tens of billions of dollars in state, local and federal subsidies and bailouts; exemptions from environmental regulations; special āBuy Americanā rules; federal pension benefit guarantees; and even its own caucus in Congress. The result: dramatic historical declines in employment and capitalization, numerous bankruptcies, and, course, continued demands for even more government protection.
In short, thereās scant evidence that Washington elites actually abandoned the Rust Belt or the American working class; their non-market interventions may have failed, but they were interventions nonetheless.
Fifth, the PNTR thesis ignores the broad and unambiguous benefits of trade and globalization more broadly. If the problems associated with the China Shock are unique to that country and time period, the PNTR and broader China Shock debate, at least on the trade side, is mostly academic: Most economists believe the China Shock has been over for years and, if its effects are unlikely to ever happen again for whatever reason, then the historical analysis, while interesting, is not very instructive regarding future trade policy changes. As one recent paper on the issue concluded, ā[t]he literature on the local labour market effects of Chinese import competition has been cited extensively as an argument for limiting trade with China despite the fact that the results do not support this conclusionā¦. even if policy were narrowly focused on direct import competition effects ignoring price and indirect effects, there is no case for limiting trade with China [because] US local labour market adjustment to the China Shock has largely concluded.ā There also will never be an āIndia shockā or āVietnam shock,ā so no use resetting American trade policy in preparation for that moment.
On the other hand, if the PNTR thesis is, as some intend, a guide for future U.S. decision-making on trade and globalization more broadly (Carlson, for what itās worth, certainly seems to be aiming wider), then we also need go beyond China and acknowledgeā
The wide body of research showing significant economic benefitsāincluding for the working classāfrom import liberalization and multilateral trade (the WTO) generally, and the overwhelming support from economists from the left, right and center (even the China shock authors);
The unseen benefits of import competition on American economic dynamism;
How trade contributes to the eradication of global poverty;
The basic morality of freer trade and the obvious problems with government putting the desires of producers above those of consumers;
The fact that much of āglobalizationā is not driven by elite policy choices (trade liberalization) at all, but by seismic changes in communications and technology (like shipping containers);
The longstanding geopolitical benefits of trade (calming problems that ushered in the GATT/WTO to begin with);
The truly unique (hopefully) moment that was the post-WWII world, with large portions either recovering from war or descending into communism, for American manufacturing and workers;
The fact that, historically, technology (not the trade balance) has been responsible for most of the low/middle-skill manufacturing job-losses and would eventually have accounted for the others too (see, e.g., this Ball State report on the relative automation risks to future U.S. employment across the country; or where all those American coal mining, automotive or steelmaking jobs really went); and
That trade economists have for decades acknowledged that adjustment to trade shocks āmay be neither quick nor easy.ā
None of this is to say that free trade is costless, or that some economists didnāt underestimate regional labor market frictions in response to largescale trade disruptions, butāunless the China Shock is truly sui generis (and in that case see above) āthe aforementioned points are essential to any discussion of trade liberalization, elite policy choices, and the American working class.
Conveniently, they often seem to be missing.
Sixth, the PNTR thesis ignores the problems with the only trade policy alternativeāprotectionism. Calling ānormalized tradeā a āchoiceā necessarily implies an alternative. In the case of trade policy (as opposed to labor and other policies noted above), that alternative is protectionism (i.e., government restrictions on imports of goods and services) in some form or another. There is no magical third trade option, and the second one is a costly failure. For example, IMF economists recently found, based on an examination of annual data that spans 151 countries 51 years (1963-2014), that ātariff increases lead, in the medium term, to economically and statistically significant declines in domestic output and productivity,ā as well as more unemployment and higher inequality. In the case of American protectionism, moreover, there is little doubt that it imposes immense economic harms on US consumers, workers and companiesāharms that far outweigh any possible benefit to protected workers; or that it doesnāt actually protect American firms and workers over the longer term; or that it breeds elite corruption, cronyism and political dysfunction. Two instances warrant special mention in this regard:
Using special rules tied to Chinaās WTO accession, President Obama in 2009 accepted a U.S. Steelworker petition and ultimately imposed 35 percent āspecial safeguardā tariffs on Chinese tires. The result was, even under the best assumptions, a few unionized jobs saved at an annual cost to U.S. consumers of over $900,000 per job, plus a substantial increase in other, non-China imports. Today, the industryās prospects are no better. (For more on the futility of this bilateral āsafeguardā mechanism, see Phil Levy here.)
A 2017 review of all US anti-dumping investigations against Chinese imports between 1998 and 2006 revealed that the duties reduced Chinese imports and increased prices of subject merchandise in the U.S. market. However, these effects ādissipate approximately 2 years after the anti-dumping decision,ā and imports from other countries simply increased to replace the declining Chinese imports. Such results ācast doubt on the effectiveness of anti-dumping actions against China as mechanisms for protecting US producersā (and, Iād add, their workers). (See also this great Dan Ikenson review of the specific and ridiculous case of anti-dumping measures on Wooden Bedroom Furniture from China.)
In short, if one looks to restrict trade in order to Drain the Swamp and solve the problems facing Americaās working class, the cure is worse than the supposed disease.
Finally, if I may get on my high horse for a moment, itās essential to acknowledge somewhere in this tome that ānormalizingā trade with China (i.e. removing U.S. restrictions on Americansā consumption of Chinese imports) was not merely an economic and geopolitical decision but also a moral one that, whether intended or not, removed stark inequities in the previous, un-normalized (protectionist) systemāinequities that typically originated in a Washington back room full of those dastardly āelites,ā invisibly propped up certain industries and workers at most Americansā (especially poor ones) expense, and generated the aforementioned macoeconomic harms and political dysfunction. Those industries and workers had no moral claim to that government protection, nor were their living standards somehow more important than those of their fellow Americans, whether residing next door or a thousand miles away. American footwear workers, for example, quietly benefited from a long-ago government decision (dating back to Smoot-Hawley) to protect their jobs through hidden restrictions on the voluntary commercial decisions of other, unknowing Americansārestrictions that forced these citizens, especially the poor ones, to subsidize U.S. footwear jobs by paying more for shoes. Maybe, after government removed that protection, it owed the affected workers more in terms of adjustment welfare or job training. But they werenāt owed the protection itself, and the mere act of removing it was not some immoral act (as it often now claimed). It was right thing to do, and we shouldnāt pretend otherwise.
Finally, the PNTR thesis ignores that many places were hit hard by import competition yet did adjust, in part due to trade and foreign investment. A final flaw in the PNTR thesis is that the longer-term effects of the import competition vary dramatically from place to place, even in states or regions that faced similarly intense competition from Chinese imports. Many places, big and small, that were once known for low-skill manufacturing and were hit hard by import competition have since then adapted and thrived. This includes towns like Greenville-Spartanburg, S.C.; Pittsburgh; Hickory, N.C.; Warsaw, Ind.; and othersātowns full of companies that succeeded by adapting to the market, importing industrial inputs, courting foreign investment and/or selling their goods abroad. (Anyone doubting these successes need only take a drive down I-85 from Charlotte to Montgomery to see it firsthand.)
The stark differences between these thriving American towns and those still reeling from a trade shock that likely ended a decade ago strongly indicates that the problem the shock revealed wasnāt import competition butāas the China Shock authors themselves assertāa failure to adjust. The question we should therefore be asking is not āwhy did elites normalize trade with China in the 1990s?ā but rather āwhat did many American towns, companies and workers do right in the face of intense import competition, and how can local, state and federal policies encourage that important, impressive improvement?ā
Based on the above, one can divine a simpler, far-more-benign explanation for the last 20-plus years of U.S. policy: Washington elites saw little choice but to liberalize trade with China because the available alternatives were non-existent or worse, especially given the information at the time that this āchoiceā was being made. Liberalization, moreover, produced real benefits (including for American workers and the poor), while also removing gross historical inequities in the previous, more protectionist system (though I doubt many elites really cared about that). The resulting disruption and adjustment was hard for some regions and workers (certainly not for all)āharder than many elites expectedāand certainly post-liberalization policy mistakes were made (though often in the direction of less liberalization, not more). With the benefit of two decades of hindsight, moreover, maybe certain specific āWTO-plusā rules would have been drafted differently during Chinaās accession. All fine and probably true.
But asserting, as many now do (certainly not just Wilcox and Hammond), that the very real labor and cultural issues going on in America today are the āfaultā of āWashington elitesā who blithely pursued a ānaive path of normalized trade with Chinaā while dogmatically resisting āsupportā (through trade, labor or any other policies) for the working class is belied by the facts, as is casting trade liberalization more broadly as an āelite choiceā (which presumes a better alternative) that intentionally and āoverwhelminglyā benefited the rich at the working manās expense. (These arguments also, one should add, raise broader questions about the future of the American right and its views on culture, limited government and markets, but thatās beyond my pay-grade.)
Labor market and cultural disruptionsāincluding those that result from import competitionāare real. They are important. But pretending that there was a better trade policy choice than liberalization is just manifestly misguided. It assumes far too much, ignores far too much, and demands far too much. It focuses on the wrong āpolicy choiceā and could, therefore, quite easily lead to the wrong policy change. Indeed, this, in my view, is the greatest problem with the PNTR thesis: Even when coming from those who profess to be vigorously pro-trade, casting the China Shock as a trade problem and not an adjustment problem, and claiming an ignorant or heartless āeliteā absence of government interventions, has the potential to forgive the real and important failures of our policymakers, CEOs and union heads over the last two decades, while empowering those with far-less-legitimate or altruistic objectives, and thus make generating a political consensus for real policy solutions even harder.
One need only turn on cable news to see it happening right now.